r 8 The Conservative. OBSERVATIONS CONCERNING THEORY OF RAILWAY CHARGES. [ CONCLUDED FROM LAST WEEK. ] Under these circumstances what are the relations between the producer of form utilities and the railway which can place them in the maiket ? Start ing with the fact that the price is fixed and cannot be modified by the carrier , the next step is to observe that the amount that must be permitted to ac crue to the producer of utilities of form is also beyond the carrier's control. This point will be appreciated aa soon as it is stated. The producer of utilities of form must receive pricee equal to his cost of production. If this is not returned he will go out of business and will no long er furnish" ! traffic for the carrier. Rail way officers are keenly aware of this fact and are exceedingly watchful that they may not be taken unaware by changes in market conditions resulting in the unexpected diminution of the tonnage received at any point. The fol lowing quotation from a statement of methods of observing traffic movement with a view of preventing such reduc tions in its volume is very suggestive : "Now we will take up that very con siderable class of tonnage that goes to competing markets or to the same mar ket from competing points. This is not a certain and easy class to determine , but practically the distinction does exist and is very clearly marked at times. Only the traffic man is in position to know just what business it is. It will be scattered at various points along the road and may be very miscellaneous. Where once indicated by the traffic de partment , such tonnnge should be regu larly withdrawn each month from the general body to a class by itself. * * * Explanations will largely lie in market conditions. It is the business that is most sensitive to industrial and com mercial conditions , and it is the duty of the traffic man to detect at once any general tendencies and adjust his rate without delay. He generally does on the complaints of individual shippers. * * * Sometimes the fault may lie with the producing point , and the traffic manager will be us jealous to guard the business from such decline as if it were his rate that was at fault. " A full comprehension of the signifi cance of the foregoing is dependent upon the realization that it is the statement of a practical railway officer based upon an intimate knowledge of the condi tions of railway traffic and expressed in the customary terminology of current railway practice. Its essence is the clear indication that the volume of traf fic is to be controlled through the ad justment of charges and that these musl respect the interests of local producers or traffic will fail. The admonition to the rate-making officer to "adjust his rate without delay" to changed com- mercial'conditions is in agreement with the most enlightened practice. It is the practical statement of the theory of charging "what the traffic will bear" and avoiding what President Hadley las called "what the traffic will not bear. " The slight confusion of terms in the concluding sentence of the quota tion is so evident that it in no way de tracts from the obviousness of this .uterpretation. Discriminating Charges. Were there not insuperable objections ; o the general practice , even from the point of view of the least far-seeing rail way manager , it might be that the ad justment of charges so as to insure to each producer of form utilities the re- iurn of his cost of production and to the railway the highest possible revenue would be accomplished by means of separate bargains upon different terms with each consignor. Were this practi cable , the railway might collect in each case the difference between local cost of production and the prices paid by con sumers ( less , of course , other costs of handling in transit , commissions , etc. ) and thus absorb all possible local differ ential gains. This may be the explana tion of some of the discriminations among individual shippers that have caused so much complaint in the United States during the last three decades. The general imposition of the discrim inating charges which would be neces sary to effect the universal or even fre quent absorption of differential gains would be as impossible as it would be illegal and undesirable. Substantial support of this proposition might be brought forward in the form of a dis cussion of the effect upon productive industry of what producers would re gard as manifestly unfair distribution. It is only necessary to suggest this ob jection , as less complicated ones are readily available. Such discriminations are forbidden by law in the United States and , however defective may be the present enforcement of this law , it has the unquestioned sanction of an ultimately invincible public sentiment and , with regard at least to an impor tant portion of railway traffic , of com mercial customs which cannot be over come. Neither public sentiment nor public law would permit the publica tion of schedules of rates which , if observed , would have the effect of secur ing higher rates from certain producers than from others located at the same point and obtaining identical service. Those violations of law which inevitably occur under present conditions are effect ed by means of secret and usually tem porary variations from the published schedules and in nearly all instances must be supposed to have the effect of adding to the differential gains of the more favorably situated producers. Under any open , schedule of charges that may continually be applied at any point , a marginal producer is certain , sooner or later to appear. No one can be required to pay higher rates than those published , and the marginal pro ducer , if not , as is usually the case , too weak to secure concessions for his traffic , is certain , unless they are withdrawn , soon to see the special rates which he tias obtained openly promulgated as charges applicable to all business of like character received at the same point. The limit to the amount which can be collected by any carrier for any service is , therefore , the difference between the price of the commodity taken to market through its agency and the marginal cost of production of that commodity at the point whence it is shipped. It may be urged , however , that if the carrier is not satisfied that it will be profitable from its own point of view to perform the transportation upon these terms , it can withdraw from the busi ness entirely or by raising its rates force a particular marginal producer out of business and substitute another whose cost is lower. This contention is by no means wholly groundless , yet it is im portant to enumerate some of the cir cumstances and motives which lead railways to accept traffic at the lowest possible rates and occasionally mislead railway officers as to the point at which profit ceases and loss commences. Joint Cost. The primary observation in this con nection is that there is no specific cost assignable to a particular railway ser vice. A very large proportion of the expenses of railway transportation are incurred on account of numerous servi ces , many are incurred on account of all , and a very insignificant , in fact almost negligible , proportion of the ag gregate is accurately assignable to par ticular services. President Hadley ex pressed the consequences of this fact and at least one of its causes when he indicated an important distinction be tween railway competition and that of establishments having smaller proportions tions of fixed capital. He wrote : "The competition of different stores finds a natural limit. It brings rates down near to cost of service , and then stops. The competition of railroads or factories find no such natural limit. Wherever there is a large permanent investment , and large fixed charges , competition brings rates down below cost of service. " In declaring , however , that "compe tition brings rates down below cost of service , " the author of the foregoing quotation apparently sanctioned the erroneous assumption of the existence of specific costs. The fact that railway transportation presents a case of "joint cost" had not received attention at the time (1885) ( ) of the publication of the work quoted. The fact that there are no specific costs is now thoroughly un derstood and there is consequently less tendency to criticise the currently accepted belief among railway officers that anything received for a particular